Tuesday, December 30, 2014

Happy New Year 2015

A few thoughts to wrap up 2014 and then on to what I hope is a happy and prosperous New Year for us all.

My last post on Game Theory and Social Security Benefits, in which I showed that there is no dominant strategy across the board for claiming benefits, ironically grew into a discussion of which strategies people feel certain are dominant. It was a fun discussion, nonetheless, and your participation is greatly appreciated. I'm happy to keep the discussion of that post open as long as you have questions or opinions. I will tie up the topic (Social Security, not game theory) for now with a couple of thoughts.

First, since most Americans have under-saved for retirement, most will need to claim benefits right away. If you have the luxury of choice, consider yourself very fortunate and then be advised that the rules are quite complex. Unless you’re willing to spend a lot of time studying the subject, buy some software like Maximize My Social Security or find a professional adviser you can trust. I’d do both. This is one of the most important financial decisions you will make and it is, for all practical purposes, a permanent decision. You need to get it right.

Second, be cautious of analyses you read that are based on life expectancy. About half of the population of any age will live longer than their life expectancy and our goal in retirement is to be able to pay for even a very long retirement, not just until our life expectancy.

It is correct to say that if you don’t live beyond your life expectancy there is little to be gained by delaying your benefits in terms of total lifetime payments. You will receive about the same total payments if you claim at 62 and live to your life expectancy that you would receive if you claimed at 66 and lived to the life expectancy of a 66-year old. As retirees, however, we need to protect against the risk that we will live well beyond our life expectancy and that’s when delaying benefits pays off.

Planning on living to your life expectancy is like forgoing homeowner’s insurance because your house probably won’t burn down.

But there are implications of early claiming beyond total lifetime payments. If you claim retirement benefits before your full retirement age (66 for most of us Boomers), you cannot take advantage of a higher retirement benefit that might become available later, for instance. Your benefit is locked in. If you are the higher earner of a married couple and claim early, your spouse’s survivor benefit is also locked in.

If you claim at 62 and live to 70 but your widow lives to 95, your legacy might also be at risk. Imagine her picking up a smallish benefit check at 90, shaking her head and saying, “My poor departed Harry was such a sweet man, but he royally screwed my benefits.”

If any of this is news to you, get some help before claiming.

Next topic, for those of you who showed interest in Moshe Milevsky’s probability of ruin formula, remember to use real (after inflation) returns when running the model. Long term historical real stock returns, for example, should be in the 6%-ish range. Also, the results are not directly comparable to other studies, such as those by William Bengen, that use the SWR model. Those studies assume different fixed life expectancies, like 15, 20 or 30 years. Milevsky uses a life expectancy probability. While Bengen assume a life expectancy of exactly 30 years, for example, Milevsky assumes that the length of retirement is a random variable with a mean of 30 years. They’re not the same thing.

I thank everyone for reading this past year. I especially thank the reader who sent a surprise Christmas gift – it made my holiday season. I hope to see all of you in 2015 when we can continue to try to figure this thing out together.

Our goal is to make sure we can feel secure and be happy in retirement. Make sure you don't forget the “happy” part.

Happy New Year!

Friday, December 19, 2014

Game Theory and Social Security Benefits


In A Tiny Bit of Game Theory, I explained a few basics of this study of decision theory. The Social Security claiming decision provides a good example of how to analyze a financial decision with game theory.

Our Social Security game will be a stochastic game against nature in which nature decides your life expectancy, which is, when you think about it, pretty realistic. Unrealistically, we are going to assume that you will live to age 64, to age 70, or to age 95 to simplify the game.

Your choices as the player are to claim benefits at age 62, full retirement age of 66, or at the maximum age of 70. We will assume that you are a single retiree with a typical lifetime record of FICA payments. Having a spouse makes this a very different game, of course, and a lot more complex. So would adding all the claiming age options.

For payoffs, I’ll use the total estimated lifetime benefits for each claiming option according to the Social Security website at SSA.gov for a single person born in 1955 and currently earning $75,000 annually. In this first game example, we will further assume that the retiree has adequate retirement savings to support her lifestyle between retirement at age 62 and the age at which she will claim benefits.

This simplified game in matrix form with lifetime Social Security benefits payoffs in 2014 dollars will look like this:


The retiree will need to also make a decision about her overall objectives. Many game theory analyses select strategies that will avoid the worst-case loss. Prisoner’s Dilemma, for example, encourages each perpetrator to confess first and avoid the longest prison sentence. Mutually-Assured Destruction was also an attempt to minimize the worst-case scenario, a nuclear war. These are referred to as “maximin” strategies because they seek to maximize the minimum outcomes. In other words, they seek the strategy that has the best payoff from among worst-case scenarios.

Some retirees want to minimize the chances of “leaving benefits money on the table.” They decide to claim as early as possible in case they don’t live long enough to “break even”. This strategy seems wrong to me on so many levels, but to each his own. Game theory allows us to analyze the problem with a wide range of potential objectives.

The table below shows how much Social Security benefits a retiree might “leave on the table” by waiting to claim but dying before the break-even age, which in this example ranges from ages 75 to 78 depending on the claiming ages.



As you can see from the payoffs, if you won’t live very long, you will maximize your total lifetime benefits by claiming as early as possible (Table 1) and if your objective is to wring every available dollar out of the U.S. Treasury (Table 2), claiming early would be the way to go. Of course, if you’re wrong about your checkout date, you might have done significantly better by claiming at a later age.

If you live to be very old, then you will receive the greatest lifetime benefit by claiming at age 70, when benefits top out. If you plan to live a long time but don’t, you will have missed years of benefits by not claiming early.

For retirees with the “maximin” objective of protecting against the worst-case scenario, claiming at 70 is the best choice, because minimizing your benefits by claiming them at age 62 and then living well into your 90's will be very painful for a very long time. The formal name for Social Security retirement benefits is Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) and claiming as late as possible is the best use of benefits if you view them as insurance. Delaying the claim date for your benefits is the cheapest way to purchase longevity insurance.

I mentioned earlier that for this example game we would assume that the retiree has adequate resources to retire at age 62 and pay for her standard of living until she claims benefits. Another way to implement this strategy is to work longer, if you have the option.

Retirees who don’t have the option to work longer and don’t have substantial retirement savings can’t play this game. They will need to claim early because they will need the income immediately. So, you have more options with Social Security if you also have a lot of money.

I’m sure you’re shocked.

There is one other game theory concept we can introduce with this example, that of dominant strategies.

If you were offered two bets and the first bet always paid at least as much as the second bet and sometimes more, you would always choose the first bet, right? Game theory refers to the first bet as a dominant strategy and the second as a dominated strategy. Game theory tells us never to play a dominated strategy. (And, it tells us that there usually isn’t a dominant one.)

In the Social Security benefits game I have described, there is no dominant strategy that always provides the best results under all circumstances. Sometimes claiming at age 62 pays more lifetime benefits and sometimes claiming at age 70 does, depending on how long you live.

However, claiming at age 62 is a dominant strategy if the objective is merely to leave the minimum amount of benefits on the table and claiming at age 70 is a dominant strategy if the objective is to minimize longevity risk.

Note that I’m not trying to use game theory to explain the best Social Security benefits-claiming strategy. That will depend on your individual resources and goals. I’m suggesting that it provides a good framework for laying out all the options and outcomes and for clearly identifying our objectives so we don’t focus only on the most likely outcomes.

Hopefully, that supports a better decision.


Monday, December 15, 2014

A Tiny Bit of Game Theory

I’m fascinated by game theory and I’ve lately been thinking about retirement finances through that lens.

You may be familiar with three products of game theory, whether you realize it or not. The first is the strategy of Mutually-Assured Destruction, with the appropriate acronym MAD, that was developed from game theory in the 1960's as a response to the threat of nuclear war. The second is "Nash equilibrium", suggested in the book and movie, "A Beautiful Mind". (John Nash won a Nobel Prize for his work on game theory.) The other is called "Prisoner's Dilemma", a game that pits two "perps" against one another to obtain a confession that seems to part of every TV crime drama ever created.

Game theory is the study of strategic decision-making or, according to expert Roger Myerson, "the study of mathematical models of conflict and cooperation between intelligent rational decision-makers.”

I keep his book, Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict, on my desk. On days when I want to humble myself, I try to understand the math. But, there is a lot to learn from game theory even if you wouldn’t touch linear algebra with a ten-foot pole.

Game theory can model strategic decisions in a number of ways, but the simplest is by using a matrix of Player A’s strategies versus those of Player B’s. The cells of the matrix contain the payoffs for each player when each chooses a particular strategy. A pair of numbers describes the payoffs. The first of the pair (boldface) is Player A’s payoff and the second is Player B’s.

Here’s an example. In this “game”, if Player A chooses Strategy 1 and Player B chooses Strategy 2, then Player A will receive a payoff of 3 “points” and Player B will receive 0 points. Each player will look at the potential payoffs for each strategy available to her, guess what Player B might do, and choose a strategy accordingly. The outcome of the game will be determined by the contents of the cell at the intersection of the two strategies.


(In case you're interested, the game above is “Prisoner’s Dilemma”, where each player’s Strategy 2 is to confess and rat out his partner in crime. Strategy 1 is to keep silent. The payoffs are the number of years in prison, so I suppose they should be negative numbers.)

In financial planning, we rarely are interested in a game between two individuals, but a game, instead, of an individual against a system of markets with random outcomes. Game theory refers to these as “stochastic games against nature”, a phrase you may never need to hear again. On the other hand, when someone asks what you're doing about retirement, you could impress them by answering, "I'm playing a stochastic game against nature."

In these games, there will be only one payoff in each cell, since “nature” doesn’t need payoffs.

Here’s an example. Let’s say that nature has two possible strategies in a game: it can rain or not rain where you are. You, in turn have two strategies. You can carry an umbrella, or leave it at home.

If you leave your umbrella at home, there are two possible outcomes. It may rain, in which case you will get wet, or it may not rain, and you will have a good outcome. You stay dry and don’t have to lug an umbrella around for no reason.

If you choose the umbrella strategy instead of leaving it at home, you also have two possible outcomes. If it rains, you stay dry. If it doesn’t rain, you will have to carry an umbrella around all day, looking stupid and encumbered for no good reason.

A matrix to describe this game might look like this:


The correct strategy choice in this game, of course, depends on the weather forecast’s probability of rain and its accuracy. It is called a stochastic game because the outcome depends on chance. It is called a “game against nature”, not because we’re talking about rain, but because we are playing against a complex system and not against an individual. The stock market, for example, would also be included in this definition of nature.

If these were the payoffs (I made them up), at what probability of rain would you switch strategies?

I think we can gain some insight into some retirement financial decisions if we look at them from a game theory perspective. In particular, I think game theory can make us focus on all possible results of our financial decisions and not just the most likely outcomes. In my next few blogs, I’ll provide some examples from retirement finance and we’ll find out if you agree, starting with Game Theory and Social Security Benefits.



           


Friday, December 5, 2014

Think Like a Bayesian Pig

OK, one more barnyard animal theme and I promise to move on.

I spoke at the RIIA Fall Conference of retirement planners a few weeks back on the topic, "Think Like a Pig". I suggested that they view retirement from the perspective of a retiree who would actually feel pain if their retirement plan failed as opposed to the perspective of a somewhat-interested third-party. I suggest you do the same with your own retirement planning because being retired isn't quite the same as thinking about retiring one day.

It's for real.

Now, I would like to recommend a further adjustment to your view of retirement planning.

Academics often treat retirement as if it is one integrated whole that begins around age 65 and could last thirty years (spherical cow alert!). This often makes sense in an academic environment when we are trying to understand the financial process involved.

Systematic withdrawals of constant dollar amounts are a good example. We can use the strategy to study the probability of failure over 30-year periods and learn about sequence of returns risk, but implementing that strategy doesn't make sense in real life. Calculating that you can spend 4% of a million dollar nest egg, or $40,000 a year for the next 30 years with little chance of outliving your savings and then actually doing that requires that you ignore any new information along the way.

When was ignoring new data ever a good idea?

At the beginning of World War I, horse-mounted cavalry ignored new data and charged machine guns.

That $40,000 spending estimate is based on what statisticians call "prior probabilities," meaning it's the best guess from the starting gate. After retirement begins, things happen that change your probability of success. The updated probability is called the "conditional probability."

Here's an example I used in a post some time ago. Let's say that you leave Los Angeles on a flight to Honolulu and you learn from the airlines that they have attempted this flight 1,000 times and only 10 of those flights didn't reach Honolulu because mechanical problems, weather or something else forced them to return. Your prior probability of reaching Honolulu would be 99%. That looks pretty darned good.

During the flight, your crew will constantly update their forecasts based on new information, running into headwinds, perhaps, or needing to fly around storms (a good model for your retirement plan). They will continuously create a conditional probability of reaching Honolulu and if that probability drops below a certain threshold, they will return to Los Angeles.

At least, you hope they will.

Should you find yourself halfway to Honolulu and discover that a wing has fallen off your plane, the conditional probability of reaching your planned destination has just declined considerably. (That's why I hate when flight attendants announce, "We'll be on the ground shortly." I need more details than that.) Once the wing is gone, you should take little comfort from the fact that your prior probability of reaching Honolulu was actually quite high.

Retirement works the same way. You might start retirement with a million bucks and a safe spending amount of $40,000, but if your portfolio declines 50% in a bear market you need to start spending less. That original $40,000 safe spending amount flew out the window with your bear market losses. To continue spending the same $40,000 after a large decline in your savings balance is simply ignoring new information, to wit, that you have less money.

In the 1700's, Thomas Bayes thought about how new information should be used to adjust our previous expectations. Bayes Theorem essentially says that we should begin with a prior probability, like a sustainable withdrawal rate or the percent of successful flights to Honolulu in the past, and modify that original expectation in light of any relevant new data that comes along.

Relevant new data for an airplane would be like, remaining fuel, unexpected headwinds and structural integrity of the wings.

This Bayesian approach is the way we retirees should view a retirement plan. Rather than view it as one integrated whole, we should think of it as planning for a 30-year retirement based on some set of prior assumptions. After a year, we should take stock of our new life expectancy, new portfolio balance, and any changes in expected spending along with several other variables and use that new information to plan a 29-year retirement.

Rinse and repeat.

That isn't what we do when we plan on a constant-dollar spending SWR strategy. Instead, it is what Larry Frank refers to when he describes Dynamic Updating and what Ken Steiner is getting at when he explains how to re-budget your spending every year with actuarial techniques.

And, it's what Moshe Milevski's equation for the probability of ruin (also an actuarial approach, by the way) tells us: it is a function of current retirement savings balance, expected spending, expected market returns and volatility (asset allocation) and remaining life expectancy. It doesn't matter what those were back on the day you retired.

What matters is what they are today.









Friday, November 21, 2014

Hope and Your Retirement Strategy

In my last post, Are Social Security Benefits a Bond?, I pointed out that many retirees might not be willing to implement a very risky upside portfolio simply because they have an income floor to rely on. Floor-Leverage Rule goes the 100%-equity bet one better.

Three, actually.

The Scott-Watson Floor-Leverage Rule and Zvi Bodie's floor-and-upside strategy are two very different variations of the Floor-and-Upside retirement income strategy. These variations recommend different floor allocations. The basic floor-and-upside strategy, described in Risk Less and Prosper: Your Guide to Safer Investing by Zvi Bodie and Rachelle Taqqu, calls for the floor to at least cover non-discretionary expenses.

Floor-Leverage Rule takes a different approach, recommending 85% of all assets be included in the floor portfolio without regard to which expenses that might cover.

More to the point, the strategies also recommend varying allocations for the upside portfolio. I envision a reasonable, 50% equity portfolio, but Bodie, for example, recommends that the upside portfolio consist of 90% Treasury bonds and 10% long-term call options (LEAPs). (Nassem Taleb has also suggested this strategy.)  Scott and Watson go even farther, recommending a 200%-leveraged (3x) stock indexed ETF. One such fund, ProShares Ultra S&P500 (SSO), which is “only” leveraged 100%, fell 79% in the last bear market. I can’t find a 3x leveraged fund that was around back then.


You can implement the upside portfolio with any amount of risk you want. Yours will still be a floor-and-upside strategy if you implement the upside portfolio with something other than Bodie's or Scott's approach.

Why do these experts, some of the most highly-regarded in the retirement planning field, recommend such risky upside portfolios and are they a good idea?

I think these recommendations are made with the assumption that retirees with a sound floor of income will be willing to take huge risks with their upside portfolio, but I am not, and I doubt that many retirees are. I think this may be another case of the pig having a different perspective than the chicken.

They also assume that retirees value floor assets and upside assets equally, in other words, that losing their entire upside portfolio would be OK if they had an adequate floor. Floor assets and the upside portfolio are both wealth, but the upside portfolio has something that the floor assets don’t and that retirees find quite attractive — hope.

Recommendations for highly-leveraged and risky upside portfolios appear to assume that a retiree will always value guaranteed income at least as highly as they value having an upside portfolio. In other words, were they to lose most or all of their upside portfolio (a 3x leveraged portfolio is wiped out by a 33% drop in stock prices), retirees wouldn’t be overly concerned because they would still have Social Security benefits and annuities to meet their needs. But, they would also have lost their upside potential. That wouldn’t make me happy.

While I can’t produce studies that show retirees would prefer not to make a huge, risky bet with their upside portfolios, I believe we can infer that from other behavior. The evidence seems clear that retirees are generally reluctant to annuitize their entire savings at retirement, and many advisers recommend against that, as well. I believe the reasons are reluctance to give up the opportunity for improving their standard of living in a bull market (hope) and hesitance to give up all liquidity, among others. If an unforeseen expense comes along, you can't withdraw extra cash from Social Security benefits or an annuity.

If we know that retirees are reluctant to create a retirement income strategy that consists of all annuities (private or Social Security), then we should assume that they would be reluctant to risk backing into that position by losing most or all of their upside portfolio and being left with illiquid annuities. It would follow, then, that they would not be willing to make huge, risky bets with their entire upside portfolio. Although Bodie’s call options strategy makes risky bets, it does so with only 10% of the portfolio. The Floor-Leverage Rule risks losing all or most of the upside portfolio and, with it, any chance of a higher standard of living.

In Three Portfolios, I showed that considering Social Security benefits a bond forces most retirees into a much riskier upside portfolio, often 100% stocks. Many argue that a 100%-equity upside portfolio would be acceptable because the retiree has a floor to rely on, but that again assumes that a retiree values floor assets at least as highly as upside potential. I argue that at the margin, this isn’t typically the case.

Retirees may value floor assets quite highly at the beginning, but at some point they will value upside potential and liquidity more than they value more floor assets. In other words, they won’t want to fully annuitize their savings and give up the opportunity to improve their lot.

If you truly don't mind that your upside portfolio might take wild swings or it won't bother you when your call options expire worthless because you would be content with your floor, then these might be reasonable strategies for you. If you don't have an iron stomach, then investing 100% of your upside portfolio, let alone 300%, might not be the answer.

I'm not suggesting that these are inappropriate strategies for everyone; one might be a perfect fit for you. I'm pointing out that any strategy that puts your upside portfolio at high risk assumes that you would be fine with losing most or all of it, along with any opportunity you might have for improving your standard of living with stock market gains, because you have an income floor.

Are you?

A Floor-and a Lottery-Ticket strategy probably sounds better to chickens that it does to us pigs.

Hope and Your Retirement Portfolio

In my last post, Are Social Security Benefits a Bond?, I pointed out that many retirees might not be willing to implement a very risky upside portfolio simply because they have an income floor to rely on. Floor-Leverage Rule goes the 100%-equity bet one better.

Three, actually.

The Scott-Watson Floor-Leverage Rule and Zvi Bodie's floor-and-upside strategy are two very different variations of the Floor-and-Upside retirement income strategy. These variations recommend different floor allocations. The basic floor-and-upside strategy, described in Risk Less and Prosper: Your Guide to Safer Investing by Zvi Bodie and Rachelle Taqqu, calls for the floor to at least cover non-discretionary expenses.

Floor-Leverage Rule takes a different approach, recommending 85% of all assets be included in the floor portfolio without regard to which expenses that might cover.

More to the point, the strategies also recommend varying allocations for the upside portfolio. I envision a reasonable, 50% equity portfolio, but Bodie, for example, recommends that the upside portfolio consist of 90% Treasury bonds and 10% long-term call options (LEAPs). (Nassem Taleb has also suggested this strategy.)  Scott and Watson go even farther, recommending a 200%-leveraged (3x) stock indexed ETF. One such fund, ProShares Ultra S&P500 (SSO), which is “only” leveraged 100%, fell 79% in the last bear market. I can’t find a 3x leveraged fund that was around back then.


You can implement the upside portfolio with any amount of risk you want. Yours will still be a floor-and-upside strategy if you implement the upside portfolio with something other than Bodie's or Scott's approach.

Why do these experts, some of the most highly-regarded in the retirement planning field, recommend such risky upside portfolios and are they a good idea?

I think these recommendations are made with the assumption that retirees with a sound floor of income will be willing to take huge risks with their upside portfolio, but I am not, and I doubt that many retirees are. I think this may be another case of the pig having a different perspective than the chicken.

They also assume that retirees value floor assets and upside assets equally, in other words, that losing their entire upside portfolio would be OK if they had an adequate floor. Floor assets and the upside portfolio are both wealth, but the upside portfolio has something that the floor assets don’t and that retirees find quite attractive — hope.

Recommendations for highly-leveraged and risky upside portfolios appear to assume that a retiree will always value guaranteed income at least as highly as they value having an upside portfolio. In other words, were they to lose most or all of their upside portfolio (a 3x leveraged portfolio is wiped out by a 33% drop in stock prices), retirees wouldn’t be overly concerned because they would still have Social Security benefits and annuities to meet their needs. But, they would also have lost their upside potential. That wouldn’t make me happy.

While I can’t produce studies that show retirees would prefer not to make a huge, risky bet with their upside portfolios, I believe we can infer that from other behavior. The evidence seems clear that retirees are generally reluctant to annuitize their entire savings at retirement, and many advisers recommend against that, as well. I believe the reasons are reluctance to give up the opportunity for improving their standard of living in a bull market (hope) and hesitance to give up all liquidity, among others. If an unforeseen expense comes along, you can't withdraw extra cash from Social Security benefits or an annuity.

If we know that retirees are reluctant to create a retirement income strategy that consists of all annuities (private or Social Security), then we should assume that they would be reluctant to risk backing into that position by losing most or all of their upside portfolio and being left with illiquid annuities. It would follow, then, that they would not be willing to make huge, risky bets with their entire upside portfolio. Although Bodie’s call options strategy makes risky bets, it does so with only 10% of the portfolio. The Floor-Leverage Rule risks losing all or most of the upside portfolio and, with it, any chance of a higher standard of living.

In Three Portfolios, I showed that considering Social Security benefits a bond forces most retirees into a much riskier upside portfolio, often 100% stocks. Many argue that a 100%-equity upside portfolio would be acceptable because the retiree has a floor to rely on, but that again assumes that a retiree values floor assets at least as highly as upside potential. I argue that at the margin, this isn’t typically the case.

Retirees may value floor assets quite highly at the beginning, but at some point they will value upside potential and liquidity more than they value more floor assets. In other words, they won’t want to fully annuitize their savings and give up the opportunity to improve their lot.

If you truly don't mind that your upside portfolio might take wild swings or it won't bother you when your call options expire worthless because you would be content with your floor, then these might be reasonable strategies for you. If you don't have an iron stomach, then investing 100% of your upside portfolio, let alone 300%, might not be the answer.

I'm not suggesting that these are inappropriate strategies for everyone; one might be a perfect fit for you. I'm pointing out that any strategy that puts your upside portfolio at high risk assumes that you would be fine with losing most or all of it, along with any opportunity you might have for improving your standard of living with stock market gains, because you have an income floor.

Are you?

A Floor-and a Lottery-Ticket strategy probably sounds better to chickens that it does to us pigs.

Sunday, November 16, 2014

The Household Balance Sheet

The household balance sheet is one of many topics I've never quite gotten around to, but New Jersey retirement planner Michael Lonier recently offered to write a guest post and he has provided an outstanding introduction to the topic. Please check out Mike's impressive bio, too.

Enjoy!

Finding the Upside on the Household Balance Sheet

Inescapably the time comes to consider that spending from savings is different from saving from income. You survey your savings and investments, scattered across a number of accounts, and the question arises, how best to manage this money to get the best lifetime outcome for the household when you are no longer earning a high income from full-time employment?

Maybe you’re thinking about rolling over 20 or 30 years of 401(k) contributions made to an assortment of funds almost randomly picked over the years, or are holding mostly cash after exiting the market during the 2008 crisis and now realize your money needs to work harder.

How do you organize—allocate—your savings and investments? How much should you invest in stocks and bonds and keep in cash? How do you decide what is best for you?

The Answer to the Puzzle is More Puzzles

You can go with rules of the thumb, like the old chestnut “age in bonds,” possibly with +/- some number adding a veneer of math to what is essentially an arbitrary amount. You can put your money in a target date fund and pay a fund company .20% to 1.00% to use their proprietary “glide path,” which adds a costly layer of research to the age in bonds formula. (Hint: Index TDFs are cheaper.) Dig deep enough, and your head might spin over how highly researched glide paths can be so different.

You can ask an investment advisor who will give you a short quiz and categorize you as conservative, moderately conservative, moderate, moderately aggressive, or aggressive, and plug you into a model portfolio that has somehow been matched with these categories which have somehow been matched to the quiz answers you gave. If that doesn’t seem right, there are advisors who will give you a longer quiz, or more categories, like south-by-south-west, or both. And whichever direction you turn, you’ll pay maybe 1.00% a year.

Everyone has an answer to your puzzle. It’s just that they’re different answers.

If you want to figure it out yourself, you are encouraged by most experts to think deeply about your risk tolerance, how you are likely to react when the bottom falls out, how much you can afford to lose (none!), and then pick a number between 0% and 100% for stocks based on…your best guess.

Look Beyond Your Investments to Your Balance Sheet

Your savings and investments are just one part of the puzzle, one part of the resources you need to manage to get the best outcome. You need to start at a place that accounts for all of your resources, that balances what you have and what you need, revealing the weaknesses—the risk exposures—you need to overcome. Financially, the place to start is with your household balance sheet.

You are probably familiar with a simple net worth statement that sums up current financial assets and debts and provides a snapshot of solvency. A full household balance sheet for planning goes further than that. The asset side of the balance sheet includes the current value of savings and investments (financial capital), the discounted present value of expected future earnings (human capital), and the discounted present value of expected Social Security benefits and pensions (social capital). The liability side includes the discounted present value of all expected future expenses, including debt service and payoffs.

I won’t cover the details of how to calculate these present values in this post, but though it sounds intensely complicated, it’s not. It’s within the reach of anyone familiar with using Excel, and is no more involved than examining your conscious for risk and divining an asset allocation from an arbitrary formula. More importantly, it represents your specific household situation in a logical and mathematical fashion without making any leaps of faith about theoretical risk, personal inclinations, or market behavior. More math, less magic.

Let’s look at a household balance sheet constructed in this way (below). What does it tell us?


The assets on the left include $1,824,700 of financial capital (FC), which is the current value of the household savings and investments in retirement and taxable accounts. The relatively low $274,800 of human capital (HC) suggests in this instance a household nearing retirement with just a couple years of earnings remaining. Someone with ten or fifteen years of employment ahead of them might have human capital over a million dollars. Not surprisingly, the $1,977,000 present value of social capital (SC)—Social Security and pension benefits over a 30-year retirement plan—is the most valuable asset on this particular household balance sheet.

On the liability side, the present value of all expected future expenses over the life if the plan (about 33 years in this case) is shown as $3,381,400. Subtracting liabilities from assets, the balance sheet shows a cushion or surplus of $695,200.

The financial lifecycle is the process of converting human capital into a stream of income that covers ongoing current expenses while building FC and SC to cover future expenses when HC has been “spent down” going into retirement. The balance sheet shows the current relationships between savings and investments, expected future earnings, accrued social capital benefits, and expected future expenses, all either in current or discounted to current dollars. It is the definitive household financial lifecycle scorecard, and so is enormously useful in answering the question about how best to allocate household resources.

Some simple math allows us to focus on the puzzle of puzzles, the allocation of financial capital (below).


If we subtract the sum of HC and SC ($2,251,900) from liabilities ($3,381,400), we are left with $1,129,400, the amount of expenses that must be covered from savings and investments (from FC). We can call this amount ($1,129,400) the income floor, the minimum amount of FC needed to cover expected expenses. Note that the cushion of $695,200 from the balance sheet is the amount of FC above the floor (FC of 1,824,700 minus floor of 1,129,400 = 695,200 cushion). This represents, after holding back some amount for reserves, the risk capacity indicated by the balance sheet, or more simply, the upside. In this case, after holding back a reserve of $125,100 from the cushion of $695,200, the resulting upside is $570,100.

The final step is to lay this out as an allocation of financial capital, based solely on the strength of the household balance sheet (below).


Using the amounts above, the balance sheet shows an Upside/Floor/Longevity/Reserves allocation of 31.2%/61.9%/0%/6.9% (Longevity is a discussion for another day, but it generally starts with funding the deferral of SS benefits as the best deal around). Note that although this shows how much of FC can be exposed to upside risk and how much should be managed as floor, it is agnostic about how that should be done. In fact, as shown above under the “Adjusted” allocation, once you know what your balance sheet says, you can make an informed decision to expose more floor or less upside to risk, as you determine works best for you. In this case, about 9% of the floor has been allocated to upside (increasing the balance sheet upside allocation from 31.2% to an adjusted 40%), putting that much of the floor at risk—and therefore requiring careful management to prevent market losses from damaging the ability of the floor to cover expenses.

The Foundation for Solving the Puzzle

There is a misapprehension that using balance sheet risk management to allocate financial capital is somehow insurance product centric, puts safety-first above all, or is just liability matching in a different costume. It can be used to allocate any of those things, just as it can also be used to allocate a total return portfolio, a dedicated floor with upside, a bucket system, or a combination of upside portfolio, bond ladder, and insured products. All of those things are about implementation, and are independent of the mathematical determination of how much household FC should be managed as upside, floor, longevity, and held for reserve.

Balance sheet analysis comes before implementation. It replaces the narrow view of the investment portfolio and total-return allocation theories as the central focus of retirement with a broader understanding of the overall household financial situation and managing all the risks that can affect the retirement plan, not just investment risk.

The household balance sheet, not portfolio theory, is the foundation of personal financial management, anywhere in the lifecycle. A solid understanding of the household balance sheet provides the basis for a reasonable and practical way to solve the puzzle of how to best use household resources to fund retirement or reach other goals.

This is a brief introduction to a subject with a deep body of knowledge that is typically not part of an investment advisor’s agenda. For more information, check the reading list at the Retirement Income Industry Association website for links to additional readings and sources.

--Michael Lonier, RMA®






Monday, November 10, 2014

Are Social Security Benefits a Bond?

Jack Bogle has suggested in the past that Social Security benefits are like a bond and should be treated as such in his “age in bonds’ allocation strategy. His reasoning is, I believe, that having that safe stream of income allows you to take more risk by buying more stocks with the rest of your investments, and it does.

Whether or not you should buy more stocks, of course, depends on your risk capacity, risk tolerance and current wealth and spending, and not simply on your age. Just because you can buy more stocks doesn't mean that you should. I also agree that a retirement income plan should consider all of a household’s assets, including Social Security benefits.

I draw a line, however, at including the present value of Social Security benefits into the bond portion of an upside portfolio to calculate my asset allocation. That’s why I recommended considering Social Security benefits as a component of the floor portfolio in Three Portfolios and calculating the asset allocation of the risky portfolio separately.

(There is a good discussion on this topic — there usually is — in the Bogleheads forum. You will notice that most posters, despite being members of a forum devoted to the philosophies of Jack Bogle, as am I, aren't really on-board with his position in this case.) 

There are several ways in which Social Security benefits are not like a bond, and therein lies the problem.

First, we can't buy or sell Social Security benefits. If we include them in our asset allocation, we can't rebalance that allocation.

Second, for most American households, the present value of Social Security benefits is the largest component of the household's wealth, followed by home equity and then retirement savings. Treating the present value of Social Security as a bond would force most households to invest their entire savings in stocks and still not be able to achieve a reasonable asset allocation.

(The present value of Social Security benefits can be estimated by getting a quote for a life annuity from an insurance company with payouts equal to expected Social Security benefits. In today's interest rate environment, multiplying your expected annual benefits at retirement age by 20 will put you in the ballpark of their present value. For a more accurate valuation, I like Income Solutions at Vanguard.com for a quick online quote.)

Third, and perhaps most importantly, few retirees will value the present value of Social Security benefits as highly as they value an equal amount of stocks and actual bonds at the margin. They might (should) like the benefits better for a large portion of their wealth, but be unwilling to convert all of their stocks and bonds to illiquid Social Security benefits.

Retirees have expressed this preference by refusing to annuitize all of their retirement savings. It's a nearly identical scenario, given that Social Security benefits are an annuity. It stands to reason that they would be equally reluctant to back into an all-annuity position by risking the loss of much of their liquid portfolio.

Stocks and real bonds can be converted to cash to meet emergencies, to spend more in some years than others, or to take advantage of investment opportunities. If you need more money from Social Security benefits, all you can do is wait. Consequently, retirees with most of their wealth in the present value of Social Security benefits should be inclined to take less risk with their relatively small portfolio of stocks and bonds, certainly less risk than a 100%-stock portfolio would entail.

Social Security benefits reduce risk no matter how you treat them in an asset allocation because they reduce spending from a risky portfolio. The probability of a systematic withdrawals portfolio surviving decreases with more spending. Reduce spending from that risky portfolio by spending Social Security benefits, instead, and you can significantly extend the life of your savings.

In fact, reducing spending is usually a more effective way of reducing risk than is adding bonds to your portfolio. As William Bengen's chart below shows (focus on the 30-year line), unless you currently hold more than 70% stocks, adding more bonds doesn't change the SWR rate much. (If the sustainable withdrawal rate decreases, it is because SOR risk has increased, and vice versa, so a falling curve indicates more risk.) Adding bonds below a 30% stock allocation actually worsens risk.


Treating benefits as a bond in the asset allocation requires the purchase of more equities to obtain a desired asset allocation and thereby increases risk.

Here is an example of the two alternatives, considering the present value of Social Security benefits as a bond in the asset allocation as shown in the top chart below, and omitting them from that calculation in the bottom chart.

Assume a household has $250,000 saved in a 401(k). They expect $30,000 a year from Social Security benefits and can buy a similar life annuity today from an insurance company for $600,000. The household might consider their Social Security benefits, then, to be a bond worth $600,000. Let’s further assume that the household would prefer a 50% bond portfolio because they wouldn’t be comfortable with more than a 20% loss of their savings ($50,000) in a bear market crash.

The riskiest portfolio allocation this family can implement for their savings, when considering their benefits a bond, is obtained by investing all $250,000 in stocks. Doing so would still only create a 29% equity portfolio ($250,000 / $850,000), but a 100%-stock upside portfolio. They would have lost over 50% of their cash and bond value ($125,000) in the 2007-2009 market crash and 100% equities is well beyond what Bengen found to be optimal for systematic withdrawals.


Had they ignored Social Security benefits for asset allocation purposes, alternatively, they would hold $125,000 in stocks, $125,000 in bonds and would have lost about 20% of that, or $50,000, in 2007-2009.


How would income be affected in these two scenarios? In both scenarios, the retiree could spend $30,000 a year from Social Security benefits. 

In the Social Security bond scenario of the upper chart, again according to Bengen, the systematic withdrawal rate for a 100% equity portfolio would be about 3.6% of $250,000, or $9,000. That would support total annual spending of just $39,000 a year.

In the scenario without a "Social Security bond", represented by the bottom pie chart, he could spend a systematic amount from the risky portfolio of about 4.4%, according to Bengen, with a 50% equity allocation of the spending portfolio, or $11,000, for total spending of $41,000 annually.

If your are so fortunate that the present value of your Social Security benefits is a small portion of your household wealth, which is to say you are quite wealthy, treating Social Security benefits as a bond in the asset allocation will make little difference. But most American households aren't wealthy.

I recommend that you calculate your asset allocation both ways. If you’re comfortable with the equity allocation this forces on your upside portfolio, then consider Social Security benefits a bond for asset allocation purposes. If doing so would leave you with an unacceptably high equity allocation inside your upside portfolio, then consider the benefits part of your floor portfolio and manage the upside portfolio separately.

I don’t see an advantage to the Bogle suggestion. It increases risk by increasing your equity allocation. Benefits reduce SOR risk by decreasing spending from your risk portfolio no matter how you consider them in your asset allocation. The present value of your benefits can’t be rebalanced and doesn’t have the liquidity of stocks and real bonds. Total spending is decreased when you consider Social Security benefits a bond because the SWR component of income is reduced by the excessive equity allocation of the spending portfolio, from 4.4% to 3.6% of the upside portfolio in this example.

Placing the benefits in your floor portfolio and ignoring them when calculating your risky portfolio’s equity allocation, as I suggested in Three Portfolios, provides a lot more control of your savings portfolio and, in most cases, exposes you to less risk with more spending.

So, in this case I suggest you take the easy route. Consider your Social Security benefits a safe source of income and address your spending needs net of those benefits separately.


-----------------

P.S. The Yin and Yang of Retirement Income Philosophies, new from Wade Pfau's blog is great stuff!




Wednesday, November 5, 2014

RIIA Webinar -- Sequence of Returns Risk

Powerpoint slides for the Retirement Income Industry Association webinar that I presented November 5, 2014 on Sequence of Returns Risk can be downloaded here. RIIA will soon post the video of the presentation and I will provide a link to it from this page as soon as it is available.

Whether you attended the webinar or viewed it later, please post any questions in the comments section below.

Following are responses to questions that were sent to RIIA.

Q: But the risk to a saver in the sense of IMPACT to portfolio is higher nearer retirement because the value of the portfolio is typically at highest point

A: True. As I mentioned in the webinar, a typical retiree will make the largest bets at the end of saving and the beginning of spending. That’s why it’s important to lower your equity allocation during those times to place smaller bets on stocks. Sorry if that wasn’t clear. I tried to circle both areas of the graph with my cursor.

Q: Aren't portfolios in accumulation less susceptible to the order of returns as long as you rebalance into relatively underperforming assets over time...and are passive as well?

Good question! Rebalancing seems to help, at least based on historical data, in both saving and spending stages. Using the RetireEarly Homepage model, rebalancing improved a 91% failure rate to 95% with 4.7% spending in the past. But, most SWR studies rebalance, including Bengen’s original work, so the spending rates you see are probably based on rebalanced portfolios already. Not rebalancing would probably make sustainable spending rates a little smaller.

Q: Talk about bond ladders of zeros as a strategy in retirement please

A: TIPS Bond Ladders are an attempt to build a better personal annuity in a safer way than SWR, which attempts it with stocks. Treasury ladders have no credit default risk, while annuities are subject to the financial strength of the insurance company. Annuities have no residual value after you and your spouse die (there are some protection features available at a cost), but your heirs can receive any unspent TIPS bonds left in the ladder. You can’t really build your own annuity either way, since annuities pool longevity risk. You can build a 30-year TIPS Bond ladder if you can afford it, but if you live 35 years, an annuity will still provide income.

If you search my blog at The Retirement Café for TIPS Bond Ladders, you will find several posts with more information (here, for example.). I plan to write on the topic again soon, so please check back.

I would say that the major problem with TIPS Bond ladders today is their high cost, given historically low interest rates (the same is true of annuities). I’d recommend a 15-year rolling TIPS Bond ladder.

Q: Why is credit/default risk not considered in bond ladders? It was mentioned home loans from the debtor side.

A: It is considered in bond ladders if the bonds aren’t Treasuries. The U.S. government is prohibited by law from defaulting on a Treasury bond. I only recommend Treasury bonds for retirement ladders.

Q: How does this all relate to a risk-adjusted return approach to portfolio allocation? As you noted, different asset types have different returns (and even within bonds)?

A: The chart I showed from Bengen shows the effect of equity allocation on SOR Risk. It doesn’t matter how you arrive at a particular equity allocation. However you arrive at an equity allocation, it appears that you will increase SOR Risk with greater than about 70% equities.


A:  Yes. Spending directly impacts SOR Risk and taxes are more spending.

The impact of inflation on your portfolio depends on the assets you hold. TIPS and Social Security benefits are adjusted for inflation, so there is little impact. Stocks perform poorly when inflation is high, but their returns typically make up for it over the long term. Payments from a pension with no COLA adjustments would be worth less and less over time, requiring you to spend more from your risky portfolio and increasing SOR Risk by increasing spending.

Q: Any comment on Kitces analysis of how SOR risk and inflation periods have played out in history?

A: Only these. Inflation isn’t a problem for the foreseeable future. And future market returns may not look like past returns. There are more good arguments that growth will be slower than there are that it will increase. I wouldn’t bet my standard of living that things will turn out in the future the way they have in the past.

Q: Great presentation!  Followed you right to the end.  
 
A: My favorite question!

Q: It seems like sequence of returns risk is magnified in a retirement where on uses a constant dollar spending approach (Bengen).  Couldn't one solve for sequence of returns by being more flexible with their spending, such as using a constant percentage approach (theoretically never running out of money though spending could potentially decline to a low number at some point)?

A: Yes. I wrote a series at The Retirement Café entitled “Clarifying Sequence of Returns Risk” showing that a constant percentage approach is safer. But as William Sharpe says, “Isn’t it self-evident that your spending should depend on how much money you now have?”

I’ve been retired for 10 years and how much money I used to have when I first retired doesn’t seem to matter to anyone.

Q: Could one lower their sequence of returns risk by beginning retirement with a relatively low SWR level (say, 2.5%) and then slowly increasing the SWR up to the more traditional rate (about 4%) over the course of a few years at the beginning of retirement (say the first 5 years)?

A: Yes. Anything that lowers your spending from a risky portfolio lowers your SOR Risk. Some people can spend less early because they have a part-time job, for example.

Q: GREAT JOB - thanks Dirk I really like your blog!

A: We have a tie for best question!

Q: Professor Stephen Sacks and I have done some work on mitigating the effect of SOR (J. Fin'l Plng Feb 2012) using reverse mortgage credit lines.  Also, Professor John Salter and others have done similar work.  Could you comment on that? Thanks, Barry H. Sacks

A: Without commenting on reverse mortgages, because I have little exposure to them, what I do know is that they would behave much like an annuity, reduce spending from a risky portfolio, and thereby reduce sequence of returns risk.

Friday, October 31, 2014

Webinar on Sequence of Returns Risk, November 5, 2014

I will be hosting a webinar on Sequence of Returns Risk on November 5 for the Retirement Income Industry Association (RIIA). Although the primary audience is financial advisers, the content will be accessible to most do-it-yourselfers and I hope you will join me.

You do need to register in advance, which you can do by clicking here.

Please post any questions you might have in the comments section below.

I previously wrote a series of blog posts on this topic beginning with Clarifying Sequence of Returns Risk, but I hope you will join me for the webinar, too, where I will cover some new ground.

Hope to see you on November 5!

Monday, October 27, 2014

Spherical Cows

Physicists are known for sometimes oversimplifying assumptions in order to simplify the math required to solve a problem. Physicists refer to these assumptions as "Spherical Cows".

The term comes from a story about a farmer who talks to a physicist about his farm's underproduction of milk and asks if the physicist might be able to offer some advice. The physicist goes away to perform some calculations, but soon returns with an answer.

"I have a solution for your problem," he explains to the farmer, "but it only works for spherical cows in a vacuum."

We encounter a lot of Spherical Cows in retirement finance, huge oversimplifications that make the math easier.

For one, we generally assume that market returns are "normally distributed" even though we have tons of evidence that they are not. If they were normally distributed, we wouldn't see nearly as many market crashes as we do. Often we assume they are log-normally distributed, meaning the logarithms of the returns are normally distributed, but they aren't really that, either.

According to Professors Fama and French, "Distributions of daily and monthly stock returns are rather symmetric about their means, but the tails are fatter (i.e., there are more outliers) than would be expected with normal distributions."

They go on to say that longer periods, like years, conform more to a normal distribution. The 23% drop in the Dow of October 19th, 1987 was something that probably never could have happened in a single day under a normal distribution of returns, but the 37% year-long drop in 2008 was a 2.5 sigma event that might happen once every 80 years.

Their advice to investors is to expect more extreme good and bad returns than a normal distribution would seem to indicate.

So, assuming annual returns are normally distributed works fairly well, but not so with daily or monthly returns.

One of my favorite Spherical Cows is the one used to calculate sustainable withdrawal rates. SWR models assume that a mythical investor will continue to spend the same amount of money each year from savings, even after it becomes obvious that he or she is about to deplete their retirement savings. The models take a percentage, say 4%, of initial portfolio value and subtract that fixed dollar amount ($4,000 from a $100,000 portfolio in this case) from the portfolio balance every year, counting the number of years before the portfolio is depleted.

This assumption makes it far easier to build a spreadsheet than would modeling how a real investor might behave with their spending as their savings grow or dwindle.

I don't think most retirees would behave that way. Would you keep spending the same amount if you saw your savings vaporizing before your eyes? I would expect them to spend a little more when their portfolio grows and a little less when it shrinks. Spending 4% of remaining savings each year instead of a flat $4,000 a year might accomplish that, for example.

In an extreme case, say retirement savings shrink by 50% in the first decade after retiring (or, conversely, grow 50%), I suspect a lot of retirees would not only reduce their spending, but abandon the SWR strategy and look for a new adviser. Of course, by then, the retiree has locked in a lower standard of living for the remainder of her life. The life annuity she took a pass on ten years earlier would start to look pretty sweet in retrospect. Despite what you may have read, a shrunken $50,000 portfolio is not assured of doubling in size because the retiree used to have $100,000.

Every retiree will behave differently, of course, and that would be really hard to implement in a spreadsheet or any other software, so we go with the constant dollar spending models because the oversimplified model makes the math a whole lot easier.

Many financial writers argue that no one really "does it that way", meaning everyone adjusts spending based on their remaining portfolio balance instead of spending a flat amount, but I have two responses to that. If no one does it that way, then everyone in the financial press should stop saying that you can do it that way.

And second, the SWR models predict outcomes for you only if you do "do it that way". (Operations Research guys say that a model is predictive only to the extent that its policies are followed.) The SWR results aren't predictive if you do something else, like adjust spending to portfolio value changes – which apparently is what everyone is actually doing.

(In simpler terms, you can't predict the average height of American men by measuring the height of players in the NBA. That's called the unrepresentative sample fallacy. Likewise, you can't predict portfolio failure rates for people who care about their savings balance from the failure rates of mythical retirees who ignore pending ruin.)

SWR predictions work, but only for spherical cows in a vacuum, or retirees who are oblivious to their current savings balance.

Perhaps the biggest assumption we make to simplify the math is that future stock market returns will look like historical returns.

The argument that they will look similar is an inductive argument that is not strong. Inductive arguments can't prove something is true, they can only argue that something is probably true. They are also defeasible, meaning that future information can prove the conclusion wrong. As Nassem Taleb would say, it was accepted as fact that all swans were white until someone found a black one. Future market returns will mirror past market returns until they don't.

It is interesting that some authors choose various periods of U.S. historical market data upon which to base their studies instead of using it all. They say things like, "We used historical data for the post-World War II era, because market data prior to that period is not representative of the current era." If one past period of history was not representative of this one, how do we know that the author's chosen data is representative of the future era, which is, after all, the one we need to know about?

It does make the math easier, though, when we toss in that little assumption.

On the other hand, there are many strong arguments that the future won't look like the past. Wade Pfau showed that 4% sustainable withdrawals only worked in 4 of 17 developed market nations (Canada, Sweden, Denmark and the U.S., in that order), lending credence to the argument that high equity returns in the 20th Century may be an anomaly of American history not to be repeated. Wade also recently argued effectively that future safe spending rates will be closer to 3% than 4% because the current risk-free rate in the U.S. is so low. That means that both stock and bond returns will be lower in the future than they have been.

Is it safe to assume that the worst thirty-year period of stock returns in our limited history is the worst that will ever happen? Well, no, because a black swan could reset the bottom. The bottom was reset in October 1929, for example.

The 30-year period beginning in 1966 was rough on retirees, but 2007 through 2009 were bad years and their returns are currently showing up only at the end of 30-year periods, like 1979 through 2008. With sequence of returns risk, however, we know that the real damage from these years will show up in studies that begin, not end, around 2008. That will be in 2037 and, again, that's the period recent retirees should wonder about.

But it certainly makes the math easier when we assume that we have already seen the worst.

I'm not saying that the work based on these Spherical Cows is without value, because sometimes having a questionable forecast is better than having none. Sometimes, it's the best we can do, given the shortage of reliable fortune tellers. As a friend of mine is fond of saying, "Bad breath is better than no breath at all."

But I also think it's important to understand the strength of the arguments and the assumptions upon which our plans are based. Assuming you're safe because your portfolio would have survived the worst bear market in the past 50 years is a big assumption.

Friday, October 24, 2014

RIAA – Think Like a Pig

I spoke at the Retirement Income Industry Association Fall Conference in Charlotte yesterday. The title of my presentation was "Think Like a Pig" and the topic was how both the math and the mindset of retirees change after we leave the workforce.

I promised to provide a link to my PowerPoint slides on my blog today and here it is. The floor is always open for questions, whether you attended or not.

I thank RIIA for inviting me. I love public speaking. (And private speaking. And I sometimes talk in my sleep because there isn't enough time in a day to say everything I want to say.)

A few of the advisers at the conference admitted they were there because, given the title, they thought I would talk about barbecue.  I hate to disappoint, so here you go. My wife and I had dinner at Woodmill Smokehouse in Charlotte. It was outstanding.

Monday, October 20, 2014

A Geek in Manhattan

I joined Joe Tomlinson and Wade Pfau in Manhattan this past week for a panel discussion about turning assets into income after retirement. The panel was hosted by MarketWatch's Bob Powell. The video will appear on the MarketWatch website in due course.

If you are not reading these three, then you need to start. I’ve linked their names to their websites.

Heck, Nobel Laureate, William Sharpe mentioned in Advisor Perspectives that he reads Wade’s blog. I think that's a big deal. They don’t call it the “Sharpe” ratio because its pointed, you know, and then there's the Capital Asset Pricing Model. Bill has a blog, too. (And, yes, Wade reads it.)

On Wednesday evening, Joe, Wade and I sat up until well after midnight in the Algonquin Hotel lobby talking about TIPS bond ladders. (I know, right?) Wade referred to this as our own "Algonquin Roundtable." I knew Dorothy Parker frequented the hotel and that James Thurber lived there for a while, but the Roundtable was a fun piece of history to learn. My wife and I stayed there several years ago, hoping some of the "literary cool" would rub off.

The conversation was so much fun for me that I lost track of time and I swear I wouldn’t have noticed if Derek Jeter had walked into the lobby. I learned three things.

First, as you can see with the Jeter thing, I tend to exaggerate a little to make a point.

Second, I am a total geek. This was one of the most enjoyable things I've done in a while. (I am undoubtedly the only person who knows me that wasn’t already aware of that. Becoming so excited when my son gave me Mathematica should have tipped me off. My high school yearbook holds a lot of hints, as well.)

And third, while the three of us have interesting disagreements, they are largely on the fringe. On the important things, we are in complete agreement.

I mentioned during the panel discussion that I am not a huge fan of annuities, in part to bait Joe and Wade into a livelier discussion (Joe bit, Wade just smiled). And while I am not a huge fan of annuities, I am also not a huge fan of sustainable withdrawal strategies. I think we all agree that there is no single great solution to funding a retirement that could last 30 years after funding a working career that could last 40. Working 40 years to pay for 70 is a challenging problem, to say the least.

Joe is a strong advocate for life annuities. I suggest you visit his website and give them a thorough consideration. I don’t think they are right for me personally, but I believe they are ideal for people in certain situations. They are the only way to guarantee income no matter how long you live and I agree with Joe that you should purchase an inflation rider. There have been good arguments that insurance companies overcharge for this inflation protection and that is probably true. But, I wouldn’t forgo fire insurance because I thought insurance companies overcharged for it. When you need it, you need it, and insurance won’t seem too expensive if your house burns down or a tank of gas costs three hundred dollars.

The panel discussion was a lot of fun. I hope you’ll watch the video when it is available. One of my favorite clients was able to attend in person and that was a real treat for me.

Now, I’m on to Charlotte this week to speak at the RIAA conference.

Before long, I'll be back at Caffe Driade drinking lattes, reading papers and writing blogs, but this is a nice change.